The concept of a “pre-existing condition” misses the point. As a property and casualty actuary, every time I hear it I think, "If acquiring a 'pre-existing condition' is financially devastating, then why don't insurance policies pay out at the time of the diagnosis? Why do health insurers play this silly game of treating sick people like hot potatoes?" We should allow health insurers price for the individual risk. Below I'll explain how an insurance market can operate this way and still solve the pre-existing condition problem.
There are two senses in which a condition can be
“pre-existing” and I think that they get conflated in standard discussions. The
first sense is the one in which the damage has already happened. A huge expense
has been incurred, and we’re just arguing about who’s going to pay for it. The
second sense is the one in which no “event” has occurred, no “damage” requiring
treatment has been done, but the expected future cost of all insurance claims
has gone up because new information has come to light. In this second sense of
a pre-existing condition, there are no existing medical bills to pay off, but
you can expect some expensive bills in the future.
Insurance is supposed to pay for catastrophic personal
expenses, the kind that it’s not feasible to budget for. The loss of a home or
medical treatments that will cost tens of thousands of dollars, for
example. For insurance to work, people have to be covered by an insurance
policy at the time of the loss. It would make no sense for me to waltz into my
local insurance agent the day after I crash my car and say, “I’m going to need
a policy that will pay for some extensive body work.” Or, “I just maimed a guy
before getting slapped with a DUI. Please give me an insurance policy so I can
pay for his medical bills.” Insurance companies worry about this, so they
usually make sure that they aren’t taking on such a liability. My second
hypothetical, with the DUI guy maiming another motorist and getting a new
insurance policy to cover it, would never actually happen. But the first one,
the guy needing body work, might. In the property and casualty world, insurers look for pre-existing damage to cars and homes to
make sure they aren’t taking on a liability on day one. They may tell the
customer to fix the damage, or only issue coverage with some kind of deductible
or coverage exclusion. Insurers also worry about the second sense of a “pre-existing
condition,” the characteristics of a property or property owner that make it
more likely that a claim will occur. If the insurer finds out about Mr. DUI
above, not only will they not cover the damage already done, they will charge
him more than the average risk because people with DUIs tend to be horrible
risks. He may well pay ten times as much for his policy than an otherwise
identical person with no DUIs.
So let’s get that straight first of all. “Pre-existing” can
mean “I’m trying to get someone to pay for a liability that already exists” or
“I have no outstanding liabilities, but my probability of a future claim is
significantly higher than normal.” People should state clearly which one of
these they are talking about.
Okay, but here’s the tricky part, where the two actually do
bleed into each other. Suppose that a medical diagnosis makes your insurance
premiums cost ten times as much as before, such that they become completely
unaffordable. You’re not asking someone to assume the liability for a surgery
that you’re already planning to schedule, but you are expecting some expensive
medical bills in the future that you can’t really afford out-of-pocket. Such a
huge hike in insurance premium might be just as devastating to your personal
finances as a $100,000 bill for a surgery. There are several ways to cover this
kind of pre-existing condition.
1)
The insurance payout happens when the diagnosis
comes back, not when the medical bills come in. Suppose a diagnosis for
diabetes for someone in your demographic has an expected cost of $100,000 over
the remainder of your lifetime; in this case your insurer pays you $100,000.
Honor served. The payment can be a one-shot or a structured payment, like an
annuity or something.
2)
Guaranteed renewal. The insurer provides a
renewal guarantee, such that they can’t simply drop a bad risk after new
information comes to light. This can be an automatic provision, or it can be an
endorsement the insured has to purchase. If it’s an optional provision, there
are adverse selection issues, where only people who think they will become sick
purchase the “guaranteed renewal” provision and healthy people save some money
by skipping it. But if it’s mandatory, insurance might end up being so
expensive that healthy people skip out on insurance altogether and you’re left
with a bunch of sick people in the same insurance pool and no healthy people to
subsidize them. It’s a tough call.
3)
Insurance covers future premium increases for
new conditions and diagnoses. This solution is very much like 2), but more transferable.
On getting a diagnosis of diabetes, I get either a big payout equal to my
expected future insurance premiums or a promise to pay such future premiums. I
can take this to another insurer, who will write me at a very high premium. But
that high premium isn’t financially crippling. It’s something I was insured against! (This is economist John Cochran's idea.)
4)
Longer Coverage Periods. In this solution,
neither the insured nor the insurer can cancel the policy, and the policy term
is very long. As in, a decade or more. So you don't risk getting dropped every year because your health status changed. You're "locked in" for a long time. The premium is roughly fixed, perhaps with
an annual adjustment for inflation and predictable changes (like your age
increasing, which on average has a predictable effect on your healthcare
costs). It may be difficult to enforce the non-cancellation provision on an
insured who *really* doesn’t want to pay their bills. I suspect that there is
no political will to enforce these provisions, and non-payers will be seen by
courts and politicians as sympathetic victims. But if implemented this would solve the pre-existing condition problem. At the beginning of the policy
period, the insurer simply factors in the expected cost of my getting diabetes.
Most policyholders won’t get diabetes, but a few will, and there are enough
premium-paying insureds to cover that expense.
All of these solutions have problems. Insurers are wary of
long policy terms, premium guarantees, and renewal guarantees. Insurers like to
have as many levers to pull as possible to manage their risk portfolios. If they go
insolvent because they are too constrained in their risk-management strategies, that means a lot of policyholders won’t have the financial security
they were initially promised. The
adverse selection problem looms large: people who suspect they are sick, even
if they don’t have a diagnosis yet, will be more likely to seek insurance. They
will be more likely to seek out insurance with these kinds of policy
provisions. There is also a moral hazard problem: being insured against a bad
outcome can make people more careless. For example, if I am insured against all future
premium increases, I might not be very cost-conscious when shopping for a new
policy, and just as importantly the insurer selling me the policy might *know*
I’m not cost-conscious and inflate the price. Item 1) has the problem that the
initial payout might not be high enough, or it might be *too* high for most
insureds so as to be an unnecessary expense for the average policy holder.
Needless to say, the exact policy language needs to be refined such that
insured and insurers find the terms acceptable. Neither party really wants
terms that are either too generous (which will inflate premiums and invite
fraud) or too stingy (which will leave some insureds with uncovered medical
bills). There’s a classic trade-off here.
Given all this, it’s possible for a private insurance market
to cover pre-existing conditions, so long as the patient has insurance at the
time of the diagnosis for such a condition. If the patient *doesn’t* have
insurance at the time of the diagnosis, that’s a different kind of problem. In
that case, not enough money was set aside to insure that expense. Arguing about
who should pay after the fact is kind of missing the point. Assuming we’re
talking about people who are planning to be insured and stay insured for their
adult lives, pre-existing conditions are a solvable problem. The diagnosis
itself is the insurable event, so the insurer at the time of the diagnosis should
be liable for all costs related to that condition. Ensuring that everyone is insured
all the time against the possibility of acquiring a “pre-existing condition” is
a different problem entirely. It needs to be recognized as such and discussed in different terms, because the policy implications are very different.
No comments:
Post a Comment